Development of Media
Technologies as “New Media” from the Perspective of a Critique of the Political
Economy of the Media
Manfred Knoche
University of Salzburg, Salzburg, Austria, manfred.knoche@plus.ac.at, https://www.kowi-salzburg.at/team/manfred-knoche/
http://www.medienoekonomie.at, @MedOek
Abstract: This paper
analyses the emergence and development of new media technologies based on the
approach of the Critique of the Political Economy of the Media.
First, a critical overview of approaches to the genesis and diffusion of
technologies is given. Second, the connection between media technologies and
capital accumulation is discussed. Third, the role of media technologies in capitalism
as a means of investment, production, distribution, and consumption is
analysed. Fourth, the connection between innovation, commodity aesthetics, and
planned obsolescence is discussed. Fifth, the antagonistic character of the
media system’s convergence, universalisation and diversification is shown. The
article shows that technological development is not autonomous but depends on
and is shaped by the development of capitalist society. In capitalism, factors
such as capital accumulation strategies, crises, competition, advertising and
marketing, market research, the state’s economic, technology and media
policies, and science and engineering influence the emergence and development
of new media technologies.
Keywords: new media, media
technology, technologies, Critique of the Political Economy of the Media,
planned obsolescence, capitalism
Acknowledgement: This article was first published
as book chapter: Manfred Knoche. 2005. Entwicklung von Medientechnologien als „Neue Medien“
aus der Perspektive einer Kritik der politischen Ökonomie der Medien. In Alte
Medien – neue Medien: Theorieperspektiven,
Medienprofile, Einsatzfelder. Festschrift für Jan Tonnemacher,
edited by Klaus Arnold and
Christoph Neuberger, 40-62. Wiesbaden:
VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften. Translated and published with permission by
SNCSC.
“In capitalism, the main purpose of technology is the effective organisation of capital accumulation in the form of the technical means of production” (Fuchs and Hofkirchner 2002, 161).
“We see how in this way the mode of production and the means of production are continually transformed, revolutionised, how the division of labour is necessarily followed by greater division of labour, the application of machinery by still greater application of machinery, work on a large scale by work on a still larger scale. That is the law which again and again throws bourgeois production out of its old course and which compels capital to intensify the productive forces of labour, because it has intensified them – the law which gives capital no rest and continually whispers in its ear: ‘Go on! Go on!’” (Marx 1849, 224).
“The advertisers’ strategy is to hammer it into people's heads as an unqualified desirability, indeed as a categorical imperative, that they must own the latest product on the market. In order for this strategy to be realised, however, producers have to constantly throw 'new' products onto the market (...). Built-in obsolescence increases the rate of wearing out, and frequent style changes increase the rate of discarding” (Baran and Sweezy 1966, 129,131).
The development of media technologies as “new media”[1] is analysed in this article with the help of a Critical Political Economy theory approach[2], specifically on the basis of a Critique of the Political Economy of the Media (Knoche 1999, 2001, 2002). There is no problem in theoretically and empirically justifying the fruitfulness of a capital- and politics-centred Media Economics research approach, especially since in capitalism as the globally dominant economic and societal system, the fundamentally legitimised interaction of capital (companies) and politics (state) has a central system-stabilising and system-developing function.
A realistic examination of the laws of motion of (media) capital proves to be insightful for the analysis of the development of media technologies as “new media”, as it is precisely the development of technology – usually labelled with positive and euphorically connoted buzzwords such as “technical revolutions”, “technical progress” or “innovations” and “growth” – is regarded as constitutive (as a question of existence“) for the individual accumulation of capital and the necessary safeguarding and further development of capitalism into oligopoly or monopoly capitalism (Baran and Sweezy 1966). This circumstance applies increasingly in the context of the neoliberal paradigm in economic theory, policy and practice, which also legitimises a corresponding structural change in the media industry, which is driven forward by planned action on the basis of the greatest possible capital autonomy with the market as the almost exclusive regulator in the supposed “free play of forces” with planned state support (Knoche 1999, 149-151).
In criticism of the purely diffusion-theoretical approach dominant in economic neoclassicism, which does not do justice to a deeper social science explanatory claim due to its focus on technology and supply, which is considered unrealistic, Seeger (1996/97, 45-52) places technology genesis models at the centre of research into the technisation of audio-visual media. He differentiates between constructivist and social evolutionary approaches in a socio-economic research tradition with a strong institutionalist orientation. In what seems to me to be a justified differentiation from neoclassical, constructivist, and sociological approaches, he considers it more informative to analyse the decisions and strategies of political and economic actors in the introduction, application, and implementation of the more comprehensive media systems from a socio-political point of view, following a more political science-oriented approach by Mayntz et al. on large-scale technological systems and the significance of institutional contexts (Seeger 1996/97, 48).
Based on the theoretical approach of a Critique of the Political Economy of the Media, the development of media technologies as “new media” is considered from a number of points of view which, in my opinion, are of decisive importance for a realistic analysis, but which have nevertheless received little consideration in the Media and Communication Studies-literature to date. Under these “new” aspects of Media and Communication Studies, which are in reality relatively “old” but by no means outdated – taking into account the relevant economic, political science and sociological literature – the development of media technologies is analysed primarily taking into account the following fundamental aspects and contexts:
·
The accumulation of
capital by individual entrepreneurs as a “source of meaning” and “moving force”
for the necessary global (media) technology development;
·
Overall economic
development stages of global capitalism and “system optimisation” as decisive
strategy parameters;
·
There is the interaction
of the global economic and political strategies of the means of production
industry, the media industry, and the economy as a whole: media technologies as
a means of investment, production, distribution, and consumption;
·
There is the interaction
of strategies of planned qualitative/functional innovation (“technical progress”)
and psychological/aesthetic innovation as well as of planned
qualitative/functional obsolescence (“wear and tear”) and
psychological/aesthetic obsolescence (“obsolescence”) as entrepreneurial strategies
in the sales promotion of “new media” as well as the associated problem of “technical
and social regression”.
·
There is the antagonistic
process of strategies of convergence, universalisation, and diversification as
well as the concentration/globalisation of the worldwide media system driven by
this.
In general terms, the considerations centre on the interest in providing academic explanations as to why media technologies as “new media” are successively developed (note: media technologies do not develop, they are developed) in a planned[3] way that can be observed empirically without any problems. The aim is to contribute to a theory of media technology development[4] that takes into account the realisation that these media technologies are developed in the general process of the planned successive development of any technology in the capital accumulation interests of capital owners on their behalf in close planning cooperation with state institutions.
In order to achieve
realistic academic knowledge and empirically supported theory development, an
analytical approach that understands capitalism
as a globally dominant economic and societal order as real and therefore takes its real
dominant core as the starting point for academic analyses seems to me to be
of comparatively great value for Media and Communication Studies. The
accumulation of capital and the production
methods and production (labour)
conditions necessary for its realisation as well as the necessary infinite production, sale, and
consumption of commodities[5]. As is well known, capital accumulation via profit maximisation is a very real “essential element” in
capitalism, and consequently also in the capitalist media industry, and a
frequently fundamentally legitimised, everyday economic and political
imperative for the owners of capital and dependent workers.
In developed capitalism, the type, development, and use of new (media) technologies are generally by no means determined by “random” inventions or by the desire to serve “technical progress” or the will to improve the fulfilment of human (communication) needs. The development of technology is therefore neither induced nor determined by technology (technology as “deus ex machina”) nor driven by demand or need (“consumer sovereignty”), as is often claimed. For a theory of media technology development that is not distracted by legitimising ideologies or media philosophies, but instead takes empirically proven or verifiable phenomena as the basis for theory formation, the starting point and benchmark are the defining “essential elements” of the capitalist economic and societal system, in particular[6]
·
the individual
accumulation of capital with its general susceptibility to crises;
·
state support for the
individual accumulation of capital;
·
the organisation of
production and labour (mode of production, productive forces and relations of
production);
·
the production, distribution,
and consumption of goods.
The “driving forces” influencing the development of media technology
are modelled in figure 1[7].
The dominant influencing factor is the activities of capital owners in the
private media industry to optimise individual capital accumulation based on the
capitalist mode of production by means of surplus value and commodity
production. The central parameter for the development of media technology is
the optimisation of the capital accumulation process, or more precisely: the
result of this process in the form of a return on the capital invested plus an “appropriate”
profit.
Figure 1: Factors influencing the development of media technologies as means of capital accumulation
Entrepreneurial action is primarily determined by either preventing,
overcoming, or “productively” utilising the consequences of a
large number of regularly “threatening” or real “crises”, which in
principle jeopardise profitable individual capital accumulation or (can) lead
to the devaluation or destruction of capital, in order to accelerate the
devaluation and/or destruction of competitors’ capital. Media companies operate
in competition with all other goods and service industries and under pressure
from the entire economy as an advertising industry. The development and use of
media technology is an important means of preventing and overcoming crises.
Media
technology development is driven forward by media companies in close “co-ordination”,
i.e., co-operation with the government’s economic, technology and media policies.
As the example of the introduction of private radio and television media in
Germany in the mid-1980s shows, economic policy and technology policy (the promotion
of nationwide cable and satellite technology) can be successfully pursued with
the help of or under the guise of well-co-ordinated media policy in the
interests of the industries benefiting from it. State technology policy as
economic policy also includes technology research and development subsidised
with taxpayers' money, especially in technical infrastructure (e.g.,
telecommunications), which was ultimately “supplied” to private capital as part
of neoliberal privatisation.
The
development of media technologies – which may be “valuable” in the eyes of
media users because they are (apparently) useful and satisfy their needs – is
literally worthless (not producing value) or capital-destroying for the
owners of capital if they are not sold at profitable prices in a way that
increases the capital value in the necessary quantity in the shortest possible period.
The profitable accumulation of capital is only successful if a “surplus”
(profit) is achieved through the massive sale and purchase of commodities. The
fundamental problem is that accumulation is not a one-off process of production
and sale, but that the goal of capital accumulation can only be achieved
through constant, almost infinite repetitions of this process. As this is a
cumulative process of the accumulation of constantly growing amounts of
capital, the non-value-enhancing idling of capital must be restricted or
prevented by accelerating and quantitatively expanding the process of
production and sale in order to secure the rate of
profit.[8]
From the
perspective of the individual accumulation of capital, it can be explained why
(product-specific) market research as well as advertising and marketing of
commodities, and sales and marketing strategies in general, are of central
importance in the current stage of oligopoly capitalism (Prokop 2000, 139-141)
for asserting the individual interests of capital owners in competition with
the individual interests of other capital owners in a society that is
fundamentally limited by human needs and necessities as well as by purchasing
power and the willingness to buy.
From the
perspective of the owners of capital, the development and use of changing[9] technologies are generally necessary in two ways in order to secure or expand the accumulation of capital. On
the one hand, the use of regularly changing technologies as a means
of production is necessary to change the mode of production
(mechanisation/automation as a means of strengthening the position vis-à-vis wage
earners, i.e., to “secure” the relations of production in the interests of the
owners of capital), to increase productivity and to reduce costs. On the other
hand, this process requires the use of regularly changing techniques as
a means of distribution and consumption. The incessant mass production
and sale of a multitude of different media technologies, each of which is
subject to constant change, is necessary because this is the only way to
achieve the desired accumulation of capital.
The use of changing media techniques as “new media” is indispensable for solving fundamental problems that regularly arise “anew” in the process of capital valorisation, especially for successful capital accumulators: The unprofitability of technical overcapacity and overproduction (measured in terms of sales volume) and the difficulty of avoiding overaccumulation (“unproductive” accumulation of capital) through profitable investment of surplus capital (that part of the “surplus”/profit that cannot be used profitably in previous production) (Kisker 2000, 70-71). An essential theoretical element for a realistic theory of the development of media technology is therefore the realisation that this development
·
in an inevitable[10] phased process
·
is necessarily driven
forward in the interests of capital owners.[11]
“The
conditions of the given capitalist mode of production and the inherent
inevitability of commodity production make them (the technologies, MK) at the
same time a moment of the valorisation of capital, [...] this also applies to
the process of discovering and developing the technologies themselves:
Technologies are developed and valorised as a means of producing and multiplying
capital” (Briefs 1983, 101).
In Media and Communication Studies, the problem of “new” media
technologies as “new” media has so far been discussed primarily in terms of
journalistic aspects and, in the neoclassical economic tradition, from a market
perspective with a broad restriction to the consumer sector. For a more
comprehensive academic analysis and theorisation, however, it seems essential
to consider the development of media technology in the close context of the
production of the means of production, media production, media distribution,
and media consumption.[12]
Marx’s (1885, chapters 20 & 21) distinction between the two departments of social production, means of production for productive consumption and means of consumption for individual consumption, and their functions for the reproduction and circulation of total social capital is fundamental here. In this theoretical context, the different significance of the production and consumption of media technologies becomes recognisable concerning their functional transformations at the various stages of an interacting capital accumulation process: the commodity function of media technologies for the producers of means of production (sales tend to be to the entire producing economy), their consumption/use function as fixed capital (means of production), and finally the commodity function for the media producers and the consumption/use function for the consumers.
Figure 2: Media technology transformation as universal means of investment, production, distribution, and consumption
An essential starting point for the development of a “media technology
theory” from the perspective of a Critique of the Political Economy of the Media
as a theory of structure and action is – similar to Seeger (1996/97, 54-55)
– the general, partly media-specific interaction of a “linked technology chain”
(figure 2), in the case of television as a chain of “programme contribution”,
studio/production, broadcasting/transmission, reception/use and
recording/storage/playback technology. Altmeppen, Löffelholz, Pater, Scholl and Weischenberg
(1994, 46-47, 62-66) also emphasise – for innovations and investments in
newspaper companies – the economic conditionality and the process character of
innovations as well as the far-reaching restriction to innovations that act as
triggers for “chains of effects of innovative measures” (product, process,
structural and contract innovations).
It is
precisely the combination of the use of “new technology” as a means of
production, distribution, and consumption that promotes the “consumerist circle”
(Candeias 2001, 169-174), which is advantageous for
the owners of capital, in that the reproduction of labour power in leisure
time, in addition to its “valorisation” in production time, also becomes
beneficial for profit maximisation through mass
(technological) consumption. In the perspective of a Critique of the Political Economy
of the Media, the “capitalist production process is viewed as a unity of the
labour and valorisation process” (Mendner 1975,
19-36). Consequently, the causes, types, and consequences of the development of
media technologies as “new media” are also analysed to a large extent from the
point of view of the development of the productive forces as well as the
associated working methods and conditions as a connection between the mode of
production and the ways of life.
In
general, the relationship between the production of means of production and
media production and distribution (figure 2) is fundamentally different from
that between media production and media consumption: On the one hand, there are
mutual competitive and complementary relationships between strong individual
economic capital accumulation interests within and between highly concentrated
industries, in particular mechanical engineering, electronics, chemicals,
telecommunications, cable, satellite, computers, and the Internet. (Kubicek 1984, Kubicek and Rolf
1985, Luyken 1985, Michalski 1997). Various media
technologies are developed in combination with financial and media policy
support from the state (Tonnemacher 2003a, 215-246).
On the other hand, the owners of capital in the media industry (production and
distribution) decide on the use of investment and production resources under
monopoly or competitive conditions according to microeconomic criteria. In this
context, the innovation and obsolescence strategies of the manufacturers of
means of production also play a role that should not be underestimated,
particularly since the media technology manufacturing industry generally
produces means of production as well as means of distribution and consumption
(hardware and software). The (entertainment) electronics industry not only
produces technology but also programmes (music, video). Basically, the
producers of means of production have to deal with “sophisticated
buyers whose concern is to increase their profits. [...] producers
of producer goods make more profits by helping others to make more profits”[13] (Baran and Sweezy 1966, 70, 71).
The
capital accumulation interests of individual media producers result in a
compulsion to regularly replace means of production and the associated changes
to production processes due to the constant need to reduce costs. In principle,
the aim is to delay new investments in means of production until the technical
equipment used has been amortised, in the narrower sense until it has been
written off in terms of value (for tax purposes) (Baran 1966, 152-158). As an
increase in production in previous areas of production tends to jeopardise
profit maximisation interests due to the widespread saturation of needs and
wants, surplus capital, which is a defining feature of capitalist development
as what Baran and Sweezy (1966, chapter 3) term “the
tendency of surplus to rise” (Baran and Sweezy 1966,
58-113), is transferred to rationalisation investments on the one hand and
invested in new areas of production based on “new” technologies on the other.
As the example of the development and use of “new technologies” in the press sector in particular shows, a change in technology as a means of investment and production is of eminent economic importance for the owners of capital in the first instance. Only secondarily is a subsequent change of technology as a means of distribution and consumption of significance. This also becomes clear in the chronological sequence of the development and use of changing technologies in the press sector. Since the mid-1970s, “journalism in the computer society” (Weischenberg 1982) has been driven by the interests of capital owners in “technical rationalisation” and increased productivity through the “computerisation” of newspaper production as a change in the mode of production and the relations of production. Although the economically necessary combination of media technology as a means of production with corresponding means of distribution and consumption (“online newspapers”) has long been sought in the press sector due to the enormous potential for reducing production (printing, paper) and distribution costs (Neuberger 2003, 65-66; Tonnemacher 2003b), such a combination will only be fully realised if it can contribute to the successful accumulation of capital. Concerning traditional press products, the technical pressure to innovate in the consumer sector is comparatively low, as press products are more or less short-lived consumer goods and the use of (printed) press products is not associated with technical receivers.
“The buyers experience the aesthetic
innovation as an inevitable, although fascinating, fate. […] Aesthetic
innovation, as the functionary for regenerating demand, is thus transformed
into a moment of direct anthropological power and influence, in that it continually
changes humankind as a species in their sensual organization, in their real
orientation and material lifestyle, as much as in the perception, satisfaction
and structure of their needs” (Haug 1986, 42, 44).
With the help of global neoliberal privatisation and deregulation policies, nation-states, in co-operation with alliances of states such as the European Union, have in recent decades created very large-scale opportunities for capital owners from various industries and sectors to accumulate capital with “new media”[14]. These state privatisation measures were very urgent for capital owners at the time, as there were general capital valorisation problems worldwide due to a lack of investment opportunities for “surplus” capital and, above all, due to “saturated” markets.[15] Consequently, there were areas of application for a change in media technologies in connection with the development of new spheres of capital investment and new mass markets in “new” media sectors such as “cable television”, AV media, digital radio, digital television (pay TV), telecommunications, online services, multimedia, and the Internet, as well as the development of new market segments in traditional media sectors with largely saturated markets using product variations and product diversification.
Figure 3: Chain reactions of investments and product-“innovations” in the capital accumulation process
Due to the connection between media technologies as a means of investment, production, distribution, and consumption, investment/production and product innovation constraints necessarily arise, which regularly trigger certain “chain reactions” of investment and product “innovation” in the capital accumulation process (figure 3). The driving forces here are the capital already accumulated to a high degree through decades of extremely successful profit maximisation (high degree of capital concentration), the devaluation of which is threatened by over-accumulation, overcapacity, and overproduction, combined with the danger of “saturated” (sub-)markets. In this context, the (further) development and use of old and new media technologies, i.e., production, compression/storage, transmission, encryption, and reception technologies in the past[16], present, and future, play a central role. With their help, it is possible to achieve strategic goals that are fundamental to capital valorisation in the sense of profit maximisation (Knoche 1999, 158-161). The main strategy applied, the replacement of “old” with “new” media technology, serves three main “transformation” objectives:
· Durable consumer goods are transformed into short-lived consumer goods[17].
· Durable consumer goods are transformed into consumer goods with the shortest possible shelf life.
· The expansion of the production and sale of short-lived consumer goods (“disposable camera”, retail sale of information, pay-per-view, automatic deletion of music tracks “retrieved” from the Internet after a short time, etc.).
Three basic innovation/obsolescence[18] strategies (Bodenstein 1977, 10-13; Haug 1980, 136-142, 159-170) are used to achieve these goals, which are essential for the long-term accumulation of capital (figure 4):
·
Planned functional-technical obsolescence as a real functional change/extension[19]
with regard to the basic and/or additional use-value of a product;
·
planned qualitative obsolescence as a real deterioration in use-value
(“built-in” premature wear and tear, shortening of the physical/economic
service life of products, also by omitting possible quality and durability
improvements through “pigeonholing” of available knowledge and patents);
·
planned psychological/aesthetic obsolescence as “aesthetic”
innovation/obsolescence as a conscious devaluation of use-value (“unfashioning”
of a long-lasting product that is still in use or basically usable).
Figure 4: Strategies of the means of production and consumption’s innovation and obsolescence
As a rule, these three strategies “of shortening the lifespan of products and of accelerated fashion change” are applied in combination as “capitalist laws” (Bodenstein and Leuer 1976, 204-205), whereby the interaction of innovation/obsolescence strategies of the two Marxian “departments of social production” of means of production and consumption mentioned above is also fundamental here (Glombowski 1976, 37-40, 316-340). Especially in the media sector, these combined strategies of planned functional-technical, qualitative, and psychological/aesthetic obsolescence are often realised in the form of system variations. In product systems consisting of several product elements (e.g., camera, film, projector, accessories), a central element is changed in such a way that the entire previous system becomes unusable or appears to be unusable. This strategy is known to be used in the computer sector at extremely short intervals (hardware/software/additional device combinations).
On the one hand, the planned obsolescence in the form of the
deliberately produced material “short life” (“becoming unusable” due to physical
wear and tear) of the “old” media technologies that are still in use or no
longer in use, but are still fundamentally usable, successfully
stimulates replacement or additional purchases (replacement, second and
additional devices) to a considerable extent. However, only the offer of a “new”
technology that is no longer compatible with the “old” technology, ideally
accompanied by the complete cessation of production of the “old” technology, actually makes the “old” technology “obsolete” because it is
unusable. This process creates the necessary pressure on the supposedly “sovereign”
consumers to open up new mass markets for replacement
or additional purchases. Criticising the neoclassical and neoliberal dogma of “consumer
sovereignty”, Joan Robinson, for example, concludes that “the claim that the
system of private enterprise is geared towards satisfying consumer desires is
pointless. Rather, consumers are the meadow on which entrepreneurs graze. We
have become accustomed to a system that functions for the benefit of the
producers and in which the benefit to the consumer is merely incidental”
(Robinson 1966, 69).
On the other hand, a predominantly “psychic” obsolescence is
constantly being generated in the form of “aesthetic innovations”, which act as
an “aesthetic obsolescence” within the framework of an all-encompassing “commodity
aesthetic” characteristic of capitalism, through a wide range of technical
product variations (design, equipment, reception quality, retrofitting,
functional and valorisation modifications, combination with additional devices,
etc.) (Haug 1986). This type of aesthetic innovation “becomes
the dominant force in monopoly capitalism” (Bodenstein
1977, 38) and causes consumers to subjectively lose the previously
(good) concrete use-value of media technologies, even though they are still
usable in a technical sense. It is not only concrete product-related
advertising and marketing measures that contribute to the success of such
strategies, but also a diverse, all-encompassing stimulation (via advertising,
marketing, PR, journalism, art, culture, education, upbringing) of a general
social re-evaluation process of values in the consciousness of consumers
(disdain for the “old”, appreciation of the “new”, orientation towards “fashion”,
reduction of inhibitions towards “throwing away”, overcoming thriftiness, etc.)
(Bodenstein and Leuer 1976, 227).
Similar to radio and television programmes, press products, especially daily newspapers, tend to have the advantage of being short-lived consumer goods which, as a means of communication similar to food and luxury foods, enable calculable daily, weekly etc. mass sales as “replacement purchases” – additionally secured by the form of a fixed subscription – which in turn is the prerequisite for the actually profitable advertising business. It is no coincidence that the press industry was traditionally one of the industries with the highest rates of profit.
The long-term success of the coupled
strategies of innovation and obsolescence is essential for the successful
accumulation of capital. In order to arrive at an
academic explanation of the existential necessity of the interplay of
the most diverse forms of these strategies, in particular their dominant “psychic/aesthetic”
variants, it is expedient to “analyse new phenomena in the context of a
transformation of the mode of production” (Haug
2003, 27). In doing so, it first becomes recognisable how necessary the
development and application of profitable information, communication and media technologies, in particular the
integration of electronic data processing (computers) and the Internet, is for
a mode of production that ensures the accumulation of capital. A new mode of
production based on modified means and processes of production serves to
increase labour productivity and change labour relations (the power relationship
between capital owners and wage earners in favour of the capital owners).
However, this transformed mode of production and the associated increase in the
amount of capital employed is only advantageous if the increase in product
quantities through the profitable sale of these products leads to the
realisation of capital accumulation (return flow of the capital employed plus profitability).
The higher the use of new technology increases labour productivity and the amount of capital employed, the greater the pressure on individual companies to increase product quantities and to use innovation and obsolescence strategies in order to sell their “own” products profitably in the face of market saturation and limits on demand and purchasing power (Bodenstein 1977, 32-41). But even a successful accumulation of capital creates a new production constraint insofar as “surplus” capital must be invested in new (technical) products in order to ensure the continued profitable valorisation of capital. This contradictory nature of the change in the mode of production through the use of new technologies and the associated reinforcement of the general production constraint also explains the central importance of the development of media technologies as “new media” and, in connection with this, the use of primarily “psychic/aesthetic” innovation and obsolescence strategies, which are essential for the realisation of “profitable”[20] capital accumulation. The successful application of these strategies, which simultaneously anchor capitalist commodity production in individuals’ consciousness as “advantageous” in macroeconomic and social terms, actually leads to large-scale and planned destruction of use-values (Bodenstein 1977, 39) and to “secondary exploitation” (Haug 1986, 103) in the area of consumption in addition to primary exploitation in the area of production.
The causes and types of innovation and obsolescence strategies are shown in figures 3 and 4. The general causes for the necessity of using such strategies are the goal of capital accumulation and the pressure to valorise accumulated capital. The specific causes are the consequences of the renewal of the mode of production through the use of new production processes and new means of production: the increase in labour productivity through technical rationalisation, the change in labour relations, and the increase in the quantity of capital. This process requires an increase and variation in product quantities, the profitable sale of which, necessary for the realisation of capital accumulation, can only be achieved through the interrelated use of various innovation and obsolescence strategies.
Technological change is generally in the interests of both hardware manufacturers (players and carrier/storage media) and content/programme producers. For the programme industry, there is a need to valorise content anew via new carrier media in old or new markets. Such valorisation is an economic necessity for them because, on the one hand, there is a lack of successfully exploitable new programmes and, on the other hand, successful products (“hits”) can only be sold repeatedly via new carrier media (Knoche 1999, 158-159).
The extent, sequence, and speed of the convergence and diversification processes are mainly determined by the strategies of financially strong (media) groups in highly concentrated media markets. Economically, they have the necessary capital and market power and politically they can assume favourable framework conditions and a high degree of assertiveness based on radical privatisation and deregulation policies. Consequently, the strategic role played by convergence, universalisation, and diversification in the global capital valorisation process of these companies must be examined. Above all, this means analysing which degree of convergence is more conducive or enforceable for which companies in which media sectors in the respective phases of different competitive and market strategies and which is not.
Figure 5: Media technology’s development, diversification, convergence, and universalisation
Figure 5 is an attempt to depict the development, diversification, convergence, and universalisation of media technologies as comprehensively as possible, particularly concerning the phases of this development based on key characteristics, divided into mass communication media and individual and business communication media. Vertically (from top to bottom) – also as an indication of phases over time – the complementary developments of “new media” are arranged as a diversification process according to the criterion of their physicality, but also according to which human senses are “newly” addressed in which combination in the course of development. The further developments within the individual media (sectors) are arranged horizontally (from left to right) according to the scale of material carriers or immaterial transmission.
The process of technical change in the media and the associated (partial) convergence/universalisation process should be shown in its basic features. In principle, four strategies for the planned successive change of media technologies can be recognised empirically based on the development to date[21]:
·
additional media types,
differentiated according to forms of communication (in the area of mass
communication: book, press, film, radio, television, audio, video);
·
per media type, a
development of generations through a change of physical carriers and/or
transmission channels, e.g. cable, satellite, online,
M-TV or record, CD, DVD (not shown in figure 5 for reasons of clarity);
·
a diversification of models
per media type and generation (not shown in figure 5 for reasons of clarity);
·
per media type,
generation, and model, partial convergence/universalisation across
different reception devices and transmission channels
(television/cable/satellite, computer/Internet, mobile phone/mobile
communications).
The process of convergence/universalisation (Knoche 1999, 165-172) has become possible in particular based on the cross-media digitisation of production and transmission and is being driven forward based on cable, Internet, and mobile phone technology. For example, the future of audio-visual media technology (production, distribution, consumption) is determined by the convergence and diversification strategies of well-funded companies in the interested industries, primarily the film/video/television and music industries (production and distribution), the electronics, chemical and computer industries (hardware), and the telecommunications industry (distribution). A distinction must be drawn between the technical, economic, institutional-organisational, content-related, and functional convergence of traditionally separate individual, business and mass communication.
The traditional diversification into
different media sectors – primarily differentiated according to technical
development stages – according to the communication forms of text/image
communication (press, book), sound communication (radio, sound carrier), moving
image/sound communication (television, video, film) as well as voice and data
communication (telephone/computer) is just as important as the diversification
into different transmission channels (terrestrial, cable, satellite, telephone
network, Internet) and finally the diversification into a large number of
different carriers, film) and voice and data communication
(telephone/computer), as well as the diversification into different
transmission channels (terrestrial, cable, satellite, telephone network,
Internet). The diversification into a large number of
different carrier media and reception devices has been economically necessary
and will continue to be used in the foreseeable future to a large extent in the
interests of capital valorisation. Complementary to this, separate, “internal”
convergence processes are being driven forward for each of the traditional and “new”
media, including television, which is used as a means of diversified multiple valorisations
of media products and media technologies in the global capital valorisation
process.
Altmeppen, Klaus-Dieter,
Martin Löffelholz, Monika Pater, Armin Scholl, and Siegfried Weischenberg. 1994. Die Bedeutung von Innovationen und
Investitionen in Zeitungsverlagen. In Print unter Druck. Zeitungsverlage auf
Innovationskurs. Verlagsmanagement im internationalen Vergleich, edited by Peter A. Bruck, 37-193.
München: R. Fischer.
Aufermann, Jörg, Manfred Knoche, Bernd-Peter Lange, and
Axel Zerdick. 1977. Die Entwicklung der AV-Medien
unter dem Aspekt intermediärer Konkurrenz und Konzentration. Media
Perspektiven 77 (8): 445-454.
Baran, Paul A. 1966. Politische Ökonomie des wirtschaftlichen Wachstums. Neuwied and Berlin: Luchterhand.
Baran, Paul A. and Paul M. Sweezy. 1966. Monopoly Capital. An Essay on the American
Economic and Social Order. New
York: Monthly Review Press.
Bodenstein, Gerhard.
1977. Geplanter Verschleiß. Erscheinungsformen und Erklärungsansätze. In Geplanter
Verschleiß in der Marktwirtschaft, edited by Gerhard Bodenstein and Hans Leuer,
1-47. Frankfurt/Main and Zürich: Deutsch.
Bodenstein, Gerhard and
Hans Leuer. 1976. Gibt es geplanten Verschleiß?
Anmerkungen zu einem Gutachten sowie ein Exkurs über das weltweite
Glühlampen-Verschleiß-Kartell. In Technologie und Politik. aktuell-Magazin
5. Thema: Kartelle in der Marktwirtschaft, edited
by Freimut Duve, 204-232. Reinbek: Rowohlt.
Briefs, Ulrich. 1983. Arbeiten
ohne Sinn und Perspektive? Gewerkschaften und “Neue Technologien”. Köln:
Pahl-Rugenstein. Second edition.
Candeias, Mario. 2001. Arbeit, Hochtechnologie und
Hegemonie im Neoliberalismus. In Ein neuer Kapitalismus? Akkumulationsregime
– Shareholder Society – Neoliberalismus und Neue Sozialdemokratie, edited by Mario Candeias and Frank Deppe, 150-179. Hamburg: VSA.
de Bens, Elsa and Manfred Knoche. Eds. 1987. Electronic Mass Media In Europe. Prospects and Developments. A Report from the FAST Programme of the Commission of the European Communities. Dordrecht, Boston, Lancaster and Tokyo: D. Reidel Publishing Company.
Emenlauer-Blömers, Eva and Thomas Muntschick. 1984. Linke und Neue Medien. In Neue Medien und
Technologien – Wie damit umgehen? Beiträge zu einer Strategiedebatte,
110-136. Berlin: Die Arbeitswelt.
Fuchs, Christian and
Wolfgang Hofkirchner. 2002. Postfordistische Globalisierung. Z – Zeitschrift
Marxistische Erneuerung 50 (13): 152-165.
Glombowski, Jörg. 1976. Ansätze zu einer Theorie der
geplanten Obsoleszenz. Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Dissertation. Berlin:
Freie Universität.
Haug, Wolfgang Fritz. 2003. High-Tech-Kapitalismus. Analysen zu Produktionsweise, Arbeit, Sexualität, Krieg und Hegemonie. Hamburg: Argument.
Haug, Wolfgang Fritz. 1986. Critique of Commodity Aesthetics.
Appearance, Sexuality and Advertising in Capitalist Society. Cambridge: Polity.
Haug, Wolfgang Fritz.
1980. Warenästhetik und kapitalistische Massenkultur I. „Werbung” und „Konsum”.
Systematische Einführung in die Warenästhetik. Berlin: Argument.
Jürgens, Ekkehardt. 1976. Neues vom Hörensehen.
Zur Entwicklung neuer Audiovisions-Medien. In Massen, Medien, Politik, edited by Wolfgang Fritz Haug,
5-72. Karlsruhe: Argument.
Kiefer, Marie Luise.
2003. Medienökonomie und Medientechnik. In Medien und Ökonomie. Band 1,2: Grundlagen
der Medienökonomie: Soziologie, Kultur, Politik, Philosophie, International,
Geschichte, Technik, Journalistik, edited by Klaus-Dieter Altmeppen and Matthias Karmasin, 181-208.
Wiesbaden: Westdeutscher Verlag.
Kisker, Klaus Peter. 2000. Empörung der modernen Produktivkräfte gegen die modernen Produktionsverhältnisse im Zeitalter der „Globalisierung“. In Politik des Kapitals - heute. Festschrift zum 60. Geburtstag von Jörg Huffschmid, edited by Rudolf Hickel, Klaus Peter Kisker, Harald Mattfeldt, and Axel Troost, 65-73. Hamburg: VSA.
Knoche,
Manfred. 2021. Capitalisation of the Media Industry from a Political Economy
Perspective. tripleC: Communication,
Capitalism & Critique 19 (2): 325-342. DOI: https://doi.org/10.31269/triplec.v19i2.1283
Knoche, Manfred. 2016.
The Media Industry’s Structural Transformation in Capitalism and the Role of
the State: Media Economics in the Age of Digital Communication. tripleC: Communication, Capitalism & Critique
14 (1): 18-47. DOI: https://doi.org/10.31269/triplec.v14i1.730
Knoche, Manfred. 2005.
Medienökonomische Theorie und Ideologie im Kapitalismus. Einige
zitatengestützte Überlegungen zu Marie Luise Kiefers „Medienökonomik“ aus der
Sicht einer Kritischen Politischen Ökonomie der Medien. In Bausteine einer
Theorie des öffentlich-rechtlichen Rundfunks. Festschrift für Marie Luise
Kiefer, edited by
Christa-Maria Ridder, Wolfgang R. Langenbucher,
Ulrich Saxer, and Christian Steininger, 406-435. Wiesbaden: Verlag für
Sozialwissenschaften.
Knoche, Manfred. 2002.
Kommunikationswissenschaftliche Medienökonomie als Kritik der Politischen
Ökonomie der Medien. In Medienökonomie in der Kommunikationswissenschaft.
Bedeutung, Grundfragen und Entwicklungsperspektiven. Manfred Knoche zum 60.
Geburtstag, edited by
Gabriele Siegert, 101-109. Münster, Hamburg and London: Lit.
Knoche, Manfred. 2001.
Kapitalisierung der Medienindustrie aus politökonomischer Perspektive. Medien
& Kommunikationswissenschaft 49 (2): 177-194. https://eplus.uni-salzburg.at/obvusboa/content/titleinfo/4659155
Knoche, Manfred. 1999.
Das Kapital als Strukturwandler der Medienindustrie – und der Staat als sein
Agent? Lehrstücke der Medienökonomie im Zeitalter digitaler Kommunikation. In Strukturwandel
der Medienwirtschaft im Zeitalter digitaler Kommunikation, edited by Manfred Knoche
and Gabriele Siegert, 149-193. München: R. Fischer.
Kubicek, Herbert. 1984. Kabel
im Haus – Satellit überm Dach. Ein Informationsbuch zur aktuellen
Mediendiskussion. Reinbek: Rowohlt.
Kubicek, Herbert and
Arno Rolf. 1985. Mikropolis. Mit Computernetzen in die „Informationsgesellschaft“.
Pläne der Deutschen Bundespost. Wirtschaftliche Hintergründe. Soziale
Beherrschbarkeit. Technische Details. Hamburg: VSA.
Luyken, Georg-Michael.
1985. Direktempfangbare Rundfunksatelliten.
Erklärung, Kritik und Alternativen zu einem „neuen Medium“. Frankfurt/Main and New York: Campus.
Marx, Karl. 1885. Capital Volume II. London: Penguin.
Marx, Karl. 1849. Wage Labour and Capital.
In Marx & Engels Collected Works (MECW) Volume 9, 197-228. London: Lawrence & Wishart.
Mendner, Jürgen. 1975. Technologische Entwicklung und
Arbeitsprozess. Zur reellen Subsumtion der Arbeit unter das Kapital.
Frankfurt/Main: Fischer.
Michalski, Hans Jürgen.
1997. Der Telekommunikationskomplex. Politische Ökonomie der Technik- und
Infrastrukturentwicklung in der Telekommunikation. Marburg: BdWi.
Neuberger, Christoph. 2003. Zeitung und Internet. Über das Verhältnis zwischen einem alten und einem neuen Medium. In Online - Die Zukunft der Zeitung? Das Engagement deutscher Tageszeitungen im Internet, edited by Christoph Neuberger and Jan Tonnemacher, 16-109. Wiesbaden: Westdeutscher Verlag. Second, revised and updated edition.
Packard, Vance. 1960. The Waste Makers.
New York: David McKay.
Prokop, Dieter. 2000. Der Medien-Kapitalismus. Das Lexikon der
neuen kritischen Medienforschung. Hamburg: VSA.
Robinson, Joan. 1966. Die
fatale politische Ökonomie. Frankfurt/Main and Wien: Europäische
Verlagsanstalt.
Robinson, Joan. 1956. The Accumulation of Capital. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin.
Seeger, Peter. 1996/97.
Technisierung audiovisueller Medien und veränderte Strukturbedingungen für das
Massenmedium Fernsehen. In Technisierung der Medien. Strukturwandel und
Gestaltungsperspektiven, edited by Bernd-Peter Lange and Peter Seeger, 39-132. Baden-Baden:
Nomos.
Tonnemacher, Jan. 2003a. Kommunikationspolitik in
Deutschland. Eine Einführung. Konstanz: UVK. Second, updated
edition.
Tonnemacher, Jan. 2003b. Wege zur Online-Zeitung. Erfahrungen
mit den Vorläufermedien des Internet In Online - Die Zukunft der Zeitung?
Das Engagement deutscher Tageszeitungen im Internet, edited
by Christoph Neuberger and Jan Tonnemacher,
110-123. Wiesbaden: Westdeutscher Verlag. Second, revised
and updated edition.
Weischenberg, Siegfried. 1982. Journalismus in der Computergesellschaft. Informatisierung, Medientechnik und die Rolle der Berufskommunikatoren. München and New York: Saur.
Manfred
Knoche is Professor Emeritus of Media Economics at
the University of Salzburg in Austria. He studied journalism, sociology,
political science and economics at the University of Mainz and the Free
University of Berlin. He obtained his PhD (1978) and defended his habilitation (1981) at the Free University of Berlin. He
was a research assistant in the years 1974-1979 and Assistant Professor of
Communications Politics in Berlin in the years 1979-1983. From 1983 until 1994,
he was the Professor of Media and Communication Studies at the Vrije
Universiteit Brussel in Belgium, where he was also the Director of the Centre
for Mass Communications Research. From 1994 until 2009 he held the Chair
Professorship of Journalism and Communication Studies with Special Focus on
Media Economics at the University of Salzburg’s Department of Communication
Studies in Austria. He chaired the German Communication Association’s (DGPuK) Media Economics-section. He is the author of many
publications on the Critique of the Political Economy of the Media. His work
has especially focused on the critique of the political economy of media concentration and the media
industry’s structural transformations.
https://www.medienoekonomie.at,
https://www.kowi-salzburg.at/team/manfred-knoche/
Twitter: @Medoek
Wikipedia: https://de.wikipedia.org/wiki/Manfred_Knoche
https://orcid.org/0000-0002-7490-5967
[1] This
possibly somewhat strange-sounding expression of “new media” was deliberately chosen
to characterise the starting point of my analysis: Media technologies,
regardless of how old or new they really are, are regularly developed in
the interests of (media) companies in such a way that they can be used as “new”
means of production to increase productivity and can also be sold profitably as
“new media”.
[2] See
Knoche (2005) on the distinction between Political Economy theory approaches
into New Political Economy, Critical (Radical) Political Economy and the
Critique of the Political Economy of the Media. Such approaches have been
discussed for some time in the Media Economics sub-field of Media and
Communication Studies.
[3] The original competitive capitalism was
characterised by a certain “market anarchy”, but in the current oligopoly
capitalism this has necessarily been transformed into a high degree of
“orderly” individual entrepreneurial and state planned economy. The
reference to the real planned nature of the actions of economic and political
actors also seems important to me against the background of the distracting “system
legitimisation” of capitalism (because it is not a planned economy, but
a “free market economy” = good) compared to socialism/communism (because it is not
a market economy, but a centralised state planned economy = bad).
[4] On the one hand, this involves explaining why a
certain technology is made available in a certain phase, and on the other hand,
why a phased change of any, in this sense, arbitrary technologies
is necessary for the individual accumulation of
capital and for the safeguarding and development of capitalism as an economic
and societal system.
[5] In view of such a real capitalism, it
seems impossible to me, in accordance with the academically recognised
goal of being as close to reality as possible, not to start from
capitalism and its core of capital accumulation, but instead, for example, from
some imaginary systems or supposedly self-referential subsystems or from
neoclassical “invisible hands” of the market. You don't have to be a “Marxist”
to do this, but it certainly can't hurt to take note of (critical) analyses of
capitalism based on the works of Marx, as they have also been presented in
large numbers by “non-Marxists”, e.g. by Robinson
(1956).
[6] A
similar approach to analysing media technology change can be found in Kiefer,
albeit on the basis of a different theoretical background and consequently with
a completely different repertoire of terms, for example in the emphasis on
technical change as a “change in economic production systems through the
development of new or improved products, production factors, and/or production
processes” (Kiefer 2003, 184) or in the indication that the carriers of
innovations are primarily companies (Kiefer 2003, 187), and finally in the
treatment of the topic in the context of micro, meso
and macro levels.
[7] I
would like to thank Mario Jooss for his expert
research into the development of media technologies and the technical creation
of figures for this article.
[8] Other
options used to break this cycle, which tends to be dangerous for capital
owners, include withdrawing capital for the private consumption of capital
owners, reducing costs by laying off dependent workers, destroying capital by “competing
down” with other capital owners or waging successful wars.
[9] I
deliberately speak of changing (media) technologies because, in the
context of capital accumulation, it is only the necessity of change that
matters, regardless of whether it brings something new or something old. The
usual emphasis on newness or innovation has an ideological function because it
creates the impression that the use of “new” technology is always associated
with “progress” and “improvement” in the living conditions of all people.
[10] The
characterisation as inevitable is intended to express something other
than the “economic constraints” that are always put forward as “laws of nature”
by entrepreneurs, politicians, and academics for ideological reasons. This
leads to a basic dilemma of critical-academic knowledge: the more the power of
this inevitability is recognised as real and explained academically, the less
“inevitably” possibilities of escaping, changing, or implementing alternatives
to human working and living conditions are seen. This leads, for example, to
considerations and behaviours of “critical adaptation”, “dual society”, “new
old belief in progress “l” or “provocative front”. (Emenlauer-Blömers
and Muntschik 1984).
[11] I am
aware that such a theoretical element is often dismissed as unjustified
“determinism” or even as a “conspiracy theory” for what I see as obvious
reasons of a general “defensive attitude” towards criticism of capitalism. I
await the corresponding “empirical attempts at falsification” by “critical
rationalists” with interest.
[12] The
real significance of this connection can only be outlined in this article as a
suggestion for further analyses.
[13]
Manufacturers of production equipment are “helping” small and medium-sized
companies in particular to go bankrupt through the use
of innovation and obsolescence strategies.
[14] Even
if the majority of the media were not “new”, at least
their devotion to private capital accumulation was something new in many
countries, especially in Europe.
[15] These
problems have been significantly reduced by the collapse of the
socialist/communist social systems and the market liberalisation in China since
the 1990s.
[16] On the
introduction of “new AV media” (video disc, video tape, video cassette with
corresponding players) in the mid-1970s, which in its basic structures is a
model for current and future processes of introducing new media technologies,
see Aufermann, Knoche,
Lange, and Zerdick (1977) and Jürgens
(1976). In the mid-1980s dominated the international scientific discussion on
“Electronic Mass Media in Europe” (de Bens and Knoche 1987).
[17] The
transformation of durable consumer goods into short-lived consumer goods and
the decline in the lifespan of relatively durable goods are described as “a
tendential law of industrial capitalist development” (Haug
1980, 161).
[18]
Obsolescence, derived from the Latin obsolescere, means: wear and tear, obsolescence, going out of use (Glombowski 1976, 111-139: Glombowski
in this context discusses Packard’s 1962 book The Waste Makers).
[19] The
highly controversial question of whether functional changes/enhancements
to products can necessarily be regarded as improvements for the
buyer/user of the respective product, as is of course claimed in product
advertising and marketing and by many scholars, can be answered on the basis of a Critique of Political Economy in general,
but also for individual media technologies. This discussion is about the
fundamental question of technical progress (“progress euphoria/belief”) versus
stagnation or regression (“progress scepticism/criticism”) from the perspective
of the individual consumer, and therefore also about the system question (the
legitimisation of capitalism versus the criticism of capitalism).
[20] Capital
accumulation is considered “profitable” from the perspective of the individual
capital owners if a rate of profit is achieved that at least corresponds to the
macroeconomic and industry-specific average but is in any case above the level
of possible interest-based income for non-productively utilised “investment
capital”. For oligopoly and monopoly companies, however, capital accumulation
is generally only “profitable” if “extra profits”, i.e., returns above the
average, can be achieved through the use and sale of new technologies.
[21] I
consider a distinction between invention and innovation or between radical
(basic innovation, change of technological paradigm) and incremental innovation
(see Kiefer 2003, 184-185, 189-192), which in my opinion can hardly be made
with certainty in the media sector, to be less appropriate.